目前,我国大部分废旧电器电子产品流入了不具备拆解资质的非正规回收渠道,给具备拆解资质的正规渠道带来较大竞争。鉴于此,本文研究政府补贴和市场合作对正规渠道的扶持作用。一方面正规渠道可以获得回收处理基金提供的拆解补贴。另一方面,基于两种渠道不同的回收处理方式,本文引入正规渠道与再制造商合作的市场机制,即正规渠道可以转让较高质量的旧品给再制造商进行加工再制造。本文首先研究正规和非正规渠道之间的回收竞争,建立依据质量进行回收定价的博弈模型。根据两种渠道不同的处理方式划分三种竞争情景,分别求解均衡解,研究在不同质量段上两种渠道的回收定价和再制造商在旧品转让中的定价决策。随着补贴水平和再制造品价格的提高,探讨补贴机制对回收竞争的影响,分析市场合作机制对于提高正规渠道竞争能力的作用。结果发现补贴可以有效提高正规渠道的竞争力,当政府补贴不是很高时,市场合作机制可以对正规渠道发挥重要的支撑作用。
At present, most of China's waste electrical and electronic equipment (WEEE) flows into the informal recycling channel without disassembling qualification, which exerts a big competitive effect on the formal channel with disassembling qualification. Faced with the serious e-waste problem, how to support formal channel and promote the regulated WEEE recycling has become a major concern for China. In the current literature, there is a lack of research on the impact of subsidy and market cooperation on the formal channel, based on the recycling competition between formal and informal channels. This paper aims to study the role of government subsidy and market cooperation in supporting the formal channel. On the one hand, the formal channel can be provided dismantling subsidy by the China Recycling Fund. On the other hand, the different disposal methods are examined between the two channels and the market mechanism in which the formal channel cooperates with a remanufactureris introduced. As such the formal channel can sell the high-quality old products to the remanufacturer for remanufacturing. The recycling competition between formal and informal channels is firstly studied, and a game model with quality-based acquisition pricing is established. Based on the different disposal methods between two channels, three competition scenarios are set and the equilibrium solutions are solved respectively. The acquisition pricing of the two channels in different quality levels of old products and the pricing decision of the remanufacturer in the transfer of old products are examined. The influence of subsidy on recycling competition is discussed, and the role of market cooperation in improving the competitiveness of formal channel is analyzed. Furthermore, the changes of acquisition prices are a numerically simulated at different quality levels of old products in three scenarios. Based on the recycling practices in China, the recycling industry corresponding to each scenario of the model is analyzed. The results show that fund subsidy can effectively improve the competitiveness of the formal channel. When the subsidy is not very high, market cooperation can play an important supporting role to the formal channel. The demarcation point in the roles of fund subsidy and market cooperation depends on the relative value of subsidy level and the transfer price of old products for remanufacturing. When remanufactured products are more popular in the market, the transfer price provided by the remanufacturer will be higher, which can help the formal channel enhance its competitiveness in the product acquisition. Our paper provides a modeling framework for the following research based on the competition between formal and informal channels and has practical significance in promoting the regulated development of recycling industry in China.
[1] Asante K A, Agusa T, Biney C A, et al. Multi-trace element levels and arsenic speciation in urine of e-waste recycling workers from Agbogbloshie, Accra in Ghana[J]. Science of the Total Environment, 2012, 424:63-73.
[2] Bakal I S, Akcali E. Effects of random yield in remanufacturing with price-sensitive supply and demand[J]. Production and Operations Management, 2006, 15(3):407-420.
[3] Bansal S, Gangopadhyay S. Tax/subsidy policies in the presence of environmentally aware consumers[J]. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 2003, 45(2):333-355.
[4] Chan J K Y, Wong M H. A review of environmental fate, body burdens, and human health risk assessment of PCDD/Fs at two typical electronic waste recycling sites in China[J]. Science of the Total Environment, 2013, 463:1111-1123.
[5] Govindan K, Soleimani H, Kannan D. Reverse logistics and closed-loop supply chain:A comprehensive review to explore the future[J]. European Journal of Operational Research, 2015, 240(3):603-626.
[6] Guide Jr. V D R, Teunter R Y, Wassenhove L N V. Matching demand and supply to maximize profits from remanufacturing[J]. Manufacturing and Service Operations Management, 2002, 5(4):303-316.
[7] Hong Xianpei, Xu Lei, Du Peng, et al. Joint advertising, pricing and collection decisions in a closed-loop supply chain[J]. International Journal of Production Economics, 2015, 167:12-22.
[8] Krumwiede D W, Sheu C. A model for reverse logistics entry by third-party providers[J]. Omega, 2002, 30(5):325-333.
[9] Liu Huihui, Lei Ming, Deng Honghui, et al. A dual channel, quality-based price competition model for the WEEE recycling market with government subsidy[J]. Omega, 2016, 59(Part B):290-302.
[10] Mitra S, Webster S. Competition in remanufacturing and the effects of government subsidies[J]. International Journal of Production Economics, 2008, 111(2):287-298.
[11] Savaskan R C, Bhattacharya S, Wassenhove L N V. Closed-loop supply chain models with product remanufacturing[J]. Management Science, 2004, 50(2):239-252.
[12] Savaskan R C, Wassenhove L N V. Reverse channel design:The case of competing retailers[J]. Management Science,2006, 52(1):1-14.
[13] Shi Jianmai, Zhang Guoqing, Sha Jichang. Optimal production and pricing policy for a closed loop system[J]. Resources, Conservation and Recycling, 2011, 55(6):639-647.
[14] Spicer A J, Johnson M R. Third-party demanufacturing as a solution for extended producer responsibility[J]. Journal of Cleaner Production, 2004, 12(1):37-45.
[15] Sthiannopkao S, Wong M H. Handling e-waste in developed and developing countries:Initiatives, practices, and consequences[J]. Science of the Total Environment, 2013, 463-464:1147-1153.
[16] Vorasayan J, Ryan S. Optimal price and quantity of refurbished products[J]. Production and Operations Management, 2006, 15(3):369-383.
[17] Wang Feng, Kuehr R, Ahlquist D, et al. E-waste in China-A country report[R]. Working Paper,United Nations University.
[18] Wang Zhaohua, Zhang Bin, Yin Jianhua, et al. Willingness and behavior towards e-waste recycling for residents in Beijing city, China[J]. Journal of Cleaner Production, 2011, 19(9-10):977-984.
[19] Wojanowski R, Verter V, Boyaci T. Retail-collection network design under deposit-refund[J]. Computers & Operations Research, 2007, 34(2):324-345.
[20] Zhou Lei, Xu Zhenming. Response to waste electrical and electronic equipments in China:legislation, recycling system, and advanced integrated process[J]. Environmental Science & Technology, 2012, 46(9):4713-4724.
[21] 付小勇,朱庆华, 赵铁林. 基于逆向供应链间回收价格竞争的回收渠道选择策略[J].中国管理科学, 2014, 22(10):72-79.
[22] 林杰, 曹凯. 双渠道竞争环境下的闭环供应链定价模型[J].系统工程理论与实践, 2014, 34(6):1416-1424.
[23] 刘慧慧, 黄涛, 雷明. 废旧电器电子产品双渠道回收模型及政府补贴作用研究[J].中国管理科学, 2013, 21(2):123-131.
[24] 易余胤, 袁江. 渠道冲突环境下的闭环供应链协调定价模型[J].管理科学学报, 2012, 15(1):54-65.
[25] 余福茂, 钟永光, 沈祖志. 考虑政府引导激励的电子废弃物回收处理决策模型研究[J].中国管理科学, 2014, 22(5):131-137.
[26] 周垂日, 梁樑, 许传永,等. 政府在废旧电子产品逆向物流管理中的经济责任机制[J].中国管理科学, 2008, 16(S1):434-437.
[27] 朱庆华, 窦一杰. 基于政府补贴分析的绿色供应链管理博弈模型[J].管理科学学报, 2011, 14(6):86-95.